Closing America's growth deficit
Economist Michael Spence. (Getty Images)
September 21st, 2011
03:41 PM ET

Closing America's growth deficit

Editor's Note: Michael Spence, a Nobel laureate in economics, is Professor of Economics at New York University’s Stern School of Business, Distinguished Visiting Fellow at the Council on Foreign Relations, and Senior Fellow at the Hoover Institution, Stanford University. His latest book is The Next Convergence – The Future of Economic Growth in a Multispeed World. For more, visit Project Syndicate or follow it on Facebook and Twitter.

By Michael Spence, Project Syndicate

As the American economy continues to sputter three years after the global financial crisis erupted, one thing has become clear: the United States cannot generate higher rates of growth in GDP and employment without a change in the mix of the economy’s domestic and export-oriented components. Above all, this will require structural change and greater competitiveness in an expanded tradable sector.

For more than a decade prior to the crisis that began in 2008, the US economy fueled itself (and much of the global economy) with excessive consumption. Savings in the household sector declined and leveled off at about zero, as low interest rates led to over-leveraging, an asset bubble, and an illusory increase in wealth.

Government, too, dissaved by running deficits. Overall, the U.S. economy expended more than it generated in income, running a trade (more precisely a current-account) deficit, and borrowed the difference from abroad. Both household and government spending patterns in relation to income were unsustainable.

With more than ample domestic demand, considerably boosted by rapid expansion in government and health care, the U.S. economy sustained growth and employment in the face of large increases in the labor force (27 million new workers since 1990), notwithstanding the substantial headwinds created by new labor-saving information technology. Setting aside financial sustainability, the most worrying aspect of the pattern was distributional: very low wage growth in the middle-income range.

Moreover, with excess reliance on domestic demand, the structure of the US economy evolved with a bias toward the non-tradable sector (where all of the new jobs were created) and insufficient reliance on foreign demand and hence exports. That led to income and price movements that caused the tradable sector’s scope to shrink, as lower value-added links of global supply chains moved to emerging economies.

The financial crisis that began in 2008 caused a sudden stop to the unsustainable pattern on the demand side. Asset prices fell, households began a lengthy process of deleveraging, savings rose, and government – faced with falling revenues and rising expenditures on unemployment insurance – could not make up the difference.

But that pattern, too, is clearly unsustainable. The net effect is that domestic demand is dramatically lower, and overall demand (domestic and foreign) is too low. As a result, the U.S. economy has almost stopped growing, particularly as the federal government (together with state and local governments) are now reining in their own budget deficits.

A large shortfall in domestic demand stymies growth and employment in the non-tradable sector, where it is the only demand that is relevant. By contrast, the part of the tradable sector that responds to foreign demand can grow with emerging-economy growth. That is helpful, but the tradable sector, as it is currently configured, is not an employment engine.

Indeed, the U.S. economy’s structural evolution over the past two decades has made additional foreign demand inaccessible without expanding the scope of the tradable sector. The excessive domestic demand that underpinned this evolution is now gone, permanently. When deleveraging in the household sector is complete, domestic expenditure may rebound, but the savings rate will not and should not go back to zero.

Fiscal stimulus, in the form of backloading deficit-reduction efforts, might help tide the economy over while structural adjustment and expansion of competitiveness in the tradable sector proceed. But, by itself, stimulus is not the answer. Otherwise, the shortfall in domestic demand would reassert itself when the stimulus ended. The argument for a measured deficit-reduction program is to buy time for the structural shifts that will expand accessible external demand and fill in the gap in aggregate demand.

What structural adjustments are needed, and how will they occur? The pace and effectiveness of structural adaptation will be determined not only by private-sector incentives and market forces, but also by government reform and investment.

With high unemployment in many parts of the labor market, downward pressure on wages will further exacerbate the country’s already skewed income-distribution. Labor markets will eventually clear, but this will happen slowly and painfully, owing to skills gaps and other short-term mismatches.

Government cannot solve the problem alone, much less make the problem go away overnight. But government can take action that improves productivity, investment returns, and conditions for innovation, thereby increasing the pace and enhancing the long-term results of structural adjustment.

To be viable, policy measures must include comprehensive tax reform; a balanced deficit-reduction program; investment in education, skills upgrading, infrastructure, and technology; and a fully developed energy policy that anticipates rising relative energy prices as emerging-market growth enlarges the global economy to three times its current size over the next quarter-century.

For maximum impact, the targeting of some of these investments should be undertaken in collaboration with the private sector (business and labor). After all, that is most often where the relevant knowledge of the best opportunities is to be found.

Finally, to attempt this rebalancing in the current fiscal environment without tax increases (perhaps temporary measures designed to overcome the cumulative investment shortfall) would be very unwise. To do so would both impede the pace of recovery and diminish the quality of the final result.

The views expressed in this article are solely those of Michael Spence.  Copyright: Project Syndicate, 2011.

Post by:
Topics: Debt Crisis • Economy • United States

« Previous entry
soundoff (3 Responses)
  1. Walmart Ramen

    The Hoover Dam was not made from food stamps! It's the Republican way of thinking.
    Like in low taxes! It's like me quiting a DR job to work as a dishwasher! I would never have enough money
    to buy all the cement needed to make the Hoover Dam!

    Well it true! Look at the Founding Fathers they were liberals!
    They were not todays Republicans running us into the round!
    And yes the Republican Party began as a liberal party also!
    How did you think we had the money to make all the Highways & grew the USA from there?

    This does put the light on the Tea Party. They protest their own survival.
    Always on this low road! Wanting to kill unions bring down pay! People with no money cant make you rich!

    I am glad about taxing the rich! Jesus said too anyway Matthew 22:21
    Taxing the rich does not kill jobs! Look at Walmart. To pay the workers $12 HR will only cost the shopper
    if at all $0.46 a shopping trip. http://laborcenter.berkeley.edu/retail/index.shtml
    Now for Walmart to pay more taxes, what will that cost you a shopping trip if at all! $1.00?
    Get over it! look who is behind the Tea Party, Republicans!
    [youtube=http://www.youtube.com/watch?v=GO_WC0FINmA&w=640&h=390]

    September 22, 2011 at 12:24 am | Reply
  2. j. von hettlingen

    The author – "as lower value-added links of global supply chains moved to emerging economies", the working forces in the U.S. were made redundant. Now it's the people there who have the purchasing power. They buy low-end goods from countries of even cheaper labour. The Americans stand helplessly by, as their tradable sector of their economies shrinks. In light of the dense populations in the emerging markets, the U.S. should concentrate on exporting high-end products. Millions of consumers there love anything hype and spare no expense!

    September 22, 2011 at 6:15 am | Reply

Post a comment


 

CNN welcomes a lively and courteous discussion as long as you follow the Rules of Conduct set forth in our Terms of Service. Comments are not pre-screened before they post. You agree that anything you post may be used, along with your name and profile picture, in accordance with our Privacy Policy and the license you have granted pursuant to our Terms of Service.

« Previous entry
Follow

Get every new post delivered to your Inbox.

Join 4,610 other followers